Total Pageviews

Thursday 23 June 2011

Unit 3: Oligopoly - Game Theory

“When I am getting ready to reason with a man I spend one-third of my time thinking about myself and what I am going to say, and two-thirds thinking about him and what he is going to say.”



Abraham Lincoln

Click here to access a link to a game theory presentation.

A game occurs when there are two or more interacting decision-takers (players) and each decision or combination of decisions involves a particular outcome (pay-off.) The fate (or the payoff) of a player in a game depends not only on the actions of that player but also on the other players!

The Monty Hall problem!

Suppose you’re on a game show, and you’re given the choice of three doors. Behind one door is a car, behind the others, goats. You pick a door, say number 1, and the host, who knows what’s behind the doors, opens another door, say number 3, which has a goat. He says to you, “Do you want to pick door number 2?” Is it to your advantage to switch your choice of doors?



Game theory is mainly concerned with predicting the outcome of games of strategy in which the participants (for example two or more businesses competing in a market) have incomplete information about the others' intentions.
The Prisoners’ Dilemma

The classic example of game theory is the Prisoners’ Dilemma, a situation where two prisoners are being questioned over their guilt or innocence of a crime. They have a simple choice, either to confess to the crime (thereby implicating their accomplice) and accept the consequences, or to deny all involvement and hope that their partner does likewise.


Confess or keep quiet? The Prisoner’s Dilemma is a classic example of basic game theory in action!


The “pay-off” is measured in terms of years in prison arising from each of their choices and this is summarised in the table below. No communication is permitted between the two suspects – in other words, each must make an independent decision, but clearly they will take into account the likely behaviour of the other when under interrogation:-

Two prisoners are held in a separate room and cannot communicate

They are both suspected of a crime

They can either confess or they can deny the crime

Payoffs shown in the matrix are years in prison from their chosen course of action

Decisions made under uncertainty




What is the optimal strategy for each prisoner?

Equilibrium occurs when each player takes decisions which maximise the outcome for them given the actions of the other player in the game.

In our example of the Prisoners’ Dilemma, the dominant strategy for each player is to confess since this is a course of action likely to minimise the average number of years they might expect to remain in prison.

But if both prisoners choose to confess, their “pay-off” i.e. 6 years each in prison is higher than if they both choose to deny any involvement in the crime.

However, even if both prisoners chose to deny the crime (and indeed could communicate with each other to agree this course of action), then each prisoner has an incentive to cheat on any agreement and confess, thereby reducing their own spell in custody.

The equilibrium in the Prisoners’ Dilemma occurs when each player takes the best possible action for themselves given the action of the other player.

The dominant strategy is each prisoners’ unique best strategy regardless of the other players’ action

Is the best strategy to confess?

Yes, but this is still a bad outcome – prisoners could do better by both denying – but once collusion sets in, each prisoner has an incentive to cheat!


Real world applications of game theory

Game theory analysis has direct relevance to our study of the behaviour of businesses in oligopolistic markets – for example the decisions that firms must take over pricing of products, and also how much money to invest in research and development spending. Costly research projects represent a risk for any business – but if one firm invests in R&D, can another rival firm decide not to follow? They might lose the competitive edge in the market and suffer a long term decline in market share and profitability.

The dominant strategy for both firms is probably to go ahead with R&D spending. If they do not and the other firm does, then their profits fall and they lose market share. However, there are only a limited number of patents available to be won and if all of the leading firms in a market spend heavily on R&D, this may ultimately yield a lower total rate of return than if only one firm opts to proceed.

In game theory, nothing is fixed!

Conventional economics takes the structure of markets as fixed. People are thought of as simple stimulus-response machines. Sellers and buyers assume that products and prices are fixed, and they optimize production and consumption accordingly. Conventional economics has its place in describing the operation of established, mature markets, but it doesn’t capture people’s creativity in finding new ways of interacting with one another.

Game theory is a different way of looking at the world. In game theory, nothing is fixed. The economy is dynamic and evolving. The players create new markets and take on multiple roles. They innovate. No one takes products or prices as given. If this sounds like the free-form and rapidly transforming marketplace, that’s why game theory may be the kernel of a new economics for the new economy.”

The Prisoners’ Dilemma can help to explain the break down of price fixing agreements between producers which can lead to the out-break of price wars among suppliers, the break-down of other joint ventures between producers and also the collapse of free-trade agreements between countries when one or more countries decides that protectionist strategies are in their own best interest.

The key point is that game theory provides an insight into the interdependent decision-making that lies at the heart of the interaction between businesses in a competitive market – particularly those dominated by a few leading players!

John Maynard Keynes’ “The Beauty Contest”:

“...professional investment may be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the competitors have to pick out the six prettiest faces from a hundred photographs, the prize being awarded to the competitor whose choice most nearly corresponds to the average preferences of the competitors as a whole; so that each competitor has to pick, not those faces which he himself finds prettiest, but those which he thinks likeliest to catch the fancy of the other competitors, all of whom are looking at the problem from the same point of view. It is not a case of choosing those which, to the best of one’s judgment, are really the prettiest, nor even those which average opinion genuinely thinks the prettiest.

We have reached the third degree where we devote our intelligences to anticipating what average opinion expects the average opinion to be.”

J.M. Keynes; General Theory, p.156, 1936

No comments:

Post a Comment